Papers
Topics
Authors
Recent
Gemini 2.5 Flash
Gemini 2.5 Flash
119 tokens/sec
GPT-4o
56 tokens/sec
Gemini 2.5 Pro Pro
43 tokens/sec
o3 Pro
6 tokens/sec
GPT-4.1 Pro
47 tokens/sec
DeepSeek R1 via Azure Pro
28 tokens/sec
2000 character limit reached

Forming better stable solutions in Group Formation Games inspired by Internet Exchange Points (IXPs) (2008.12235v1)

Published 27 Aug 2020 in cs.GT

Abstract: We study a coordination game motivated by the formation of Internet Exchange Points (IXPs), in which agents choose which facilities to join. Joining the same facility as other agents you communicate with has benefits, but different facilities have different costs for each agent. Thus, the players wish to join the same facilities as their "friends", but this is balanced by them not wanting to pay the cost of joining a facility. We first show that the Price of Stability ($PoS$) of this game is at most 2, and more generally there always exists an $\alpha$-approximate equilibrium with cost at most $\frac{2}{\alpha}$ of optimum. We then focus on how better stable solutions can be formed. If we allow agents to pay their neighbors to prevent them from deviating (i.e., a player $i$ voluntarily pays another player $j$ so that $j$ joins the same facility), then we provide a payment scheme which stabilizes the solution with minimum social cost $s*$, i.e. PoS is 1. In our main technical result, we consider how much a central coordinator would have to pay the players in order to form good stable solutions. Let $\Delta$ denote the total amount of payments needed to be paid to the players in order to stabilize $s*$, i.e., these are payments that a player would lose if they changed their strategy from the one in $s*$. We prove that there is a tradeoff between $\Delta$ and the Price of Stability: $\frac{\Delta}{cost(s*)} \le 1 - \frac{2}{5} PoS$. Thus when there are no good stable solutions, only a small amount of extra payment is needed to stabilize $s*$; and when good stable solutions already exist (i.e., $PoS$ is small), then we should be happy with those solutions instead. Finally, we consider the computational complexity of finding the optimum solution $s*$, and design a polynomial time $O(\log n)$ approximation algorithm for this problem.

User Edit Pencil Streamline Icon: https://streamlinehq.com
Authors (2)
  1. Elliot Anshelevich (26 papers)
  2. Wennan Zhu (10 papers)

Summary

We haven't generated a summary for this paper yet.