Papers
Topics
Authors
Recent
Gemini 2.5 Flash
Gemini 2.5 Flash
156 tokens/sec
GPT-4o
7 tokens/sec
Gemini 2.5 Pro Pro
45 tokens/sec
o3 Pro
4 tokens/sec
GPT-4.1 Pro
38 tokens/sec
DeepSeek R1 via Azure Pro
28 tokens/sec
2000 character limit reached

Artificial Intelligence and Spontaneous Collusion (2202.05946v5)

Published 12 Feb 2022 in econ.TH, cs.AI, and cs.GT

Abstract: We develop a tractable model for studying strategic interactions between learning algorithms. We uncover a mechanism responsible for the emergence of algorithmic collusion. We observe that algorithms periodically coordinate on actions that are more profitable than static Nash equilibria. This novel collusive channel relies on an endogenous statistical linkage in the algorithms' estimates which we call spontaneous coupling. The model's parameters predict whether the statistical linkage will appear, and what market structures facilitate algorithmic collusion. We show that spontaneous coupling can sustain collusion in prices and market shares, complementing experimental findings in the literature. Finally, we apply our results to design algorithmic markets.

Definition Search Book Streamline Icon: https://streamlinehq.com
References (41)
  1. Abada, I. and X. Lambin (2023): “Artificial intelligence: Can seemingly collusive outcomes be avoided?” Management Science.
  2. Abreu, D. and H. Matsushima (1992): “Virtual implementation in iteratively undominated strategies: complete information,” Econometrica, 993–1008.
  3. Asker, J., C. Fershtman, and A. Pakes (2022): “Artificial Intelligence, Algorithm Design and Pricing,” American Economic Review, P&P, forthcoming.
  4. Banchio, M. and A. Skrzypacz (2022): “Artificial Intelligence and Auction Design,” Working paper.
  5. Benaim, M. (1996): “A Dynamical System Approach to Stochastic Approximations,” SIAM Journal of Control and Optimization, 34, 437–472.
  6. Bendor, J., D. Mookherjee, and D. Ray (2001a): “Aspiration-Based Reinforcement Learning in Repeated Interaction Games: An Overview,” International Game Theory Review, 03, 159–174.
  7. ——— (2001b): “Reinforcement Learning in Repeated Interaction Games,” The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, 1.
  8. Bhandari, J., D. Russo, and R. Singal (2021): “A finite time analysis of temporal difference learning with linear function approximation,” Operations Research, 69, 950–973.
  9. Borkar, V. S. and S. P. Meyn (2000): “The O.D.E. Method for Convergence of Stochastic Approximation and Reinforcement Learning,” SIAM J. Control. Optim., 38, 447–469.
  10. Brown, Z. Y. and A. MacKay (2021): “Competition in Pricing Algorithms,” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, forthcoming.
  11. Börgers, T. and R. Sarin (1997): “Learning Through Reinforcement and Replicator Dynamics,” Journal of Economic Theory, 77, 1–14.
  12. Calvano, E., G. Calzolari, V. Denicolo, and S. Pastorello (2020): “Artificial intelligence, algorithmic pricing, and collusion,” American Economic Review, 110, 3267–97.
  13. Competition & Markets Authority (2021): “Algorithms: How they can reduce competition and harm consumers,” Discussion paper.
  14. Competition Bureau (2018): “Big Data and Innovation: Implications for Competition Policy in Canada,” Discussion paper.
  15. Dieci, L. and L. Lopez (2011): “Sliding motion on discontinuity surfaces of high co-dimension. A construction for selecting a Filippov vector field,” Numerische Mathematik, 117, 779–811.
  16. Erev, I., Y. Bereby-Meyer, and A. E. Roth (1999): “The effect of adding a constant to all payoffs: experimental investigation, and implications for reinforcement learning models,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 39, 111–128.
  17. Erev, I. and A. E. Roth (1998): “Predicting How People Play Games: Reinforcement Learning in Experimental Games with Unique, Mixed Strategy Equilibria,” The American Economic Review, 88, 848–881.
  18. Gomes, E. R. and R. Kowalczyk (2009): “Dynamic Analysis of Multiagent Q-Learning with ϵitalic-ϵ\epsilonitalic_ϵ-Greedy Exploration,” in Proceedings of the 26th Annual International Conference on Machine Learning, 369–376.
  19. Gonczarowski, Y., O. Heffetz, and C. Thomas (2023): “Strategyproofness-Exposing Mechanism Descriptions,” Working paper.
  20. Hammond, P. J. (1979): “Straightforward Individual Incentive Compatibility in Large Economies,” The Review of Economic Studies, 46, 263–282.
  21. Hansen, K., K. Misra, and M. Pai (2021): “Algorithmic Collusion: Supra-Competitive Prices via Independent Algorithms,” Marketing Science, 40, 1–12.
  22. Harrington, J. E. (2018): “Developing Competition Law for Collusion by Autonomous Artificial Agents,” Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 14, 331–363.
  23. ——— (2022): “The effect of outsourcing pricing algorithms on market competition,” Management Science, 68, 6889–6906.
  24. Hopkins, E. and M. Posch (2005): “Attainability of boundary points under reinforcement learning,” Games and Economic Behavior, 53, 110–125.
  25. Johnson, J., A. Rhodes, and M. Wildenbeest (2023): “Platform Design when Sellers Use Pricing Algorithms,” Econometrica, forthcoming.
  26. Karandikar, R., D. Mookherjee, D. Ray, and F. Vega-Redondo (1998): “Evolving Aspirations and Cooperation,” Journal of Economic Theory, 80, 292–331.
  27. Klein, T. (2021): “Autonomous algorithmic collusion: Q-learning under sequential pricing,” The RAND Journal of Economics, 52, 538–558.
  28. Kurtz, T. G. (1970): “Solutions of ordinary differential equations as limits of pure jump Markov processes,” Journal of Applied Probability, 7, 49–58.
  29. Lamba, R. and S. Zhuk (2022): “Pricing with Algorithms,” working paper.
  30. Leisten, M. (2022): “Algorithmic Competition, with Humans,” Working paper.
  31. Leonardos, S. and G. Piliouras (2022): “Exploration-exploitation in multi-agent learning: Catastrophe theory meets game theory,” Artificial Intelligence, 304.
  32. Lerer, A. and A. Peysakhovich (2017): ‘‘Maintaining cooperation in complex social dilemmas using deep reinforcement learning,” arXiv preprint arXiv:1707.01068.
  33. Mertikopoulos, P. and W. H. Sandholm (2016): “Learning in games via reinforcement and regularization,” Mathematics of Operations Research, 41, 1297–1324.
  34. Musolff, L. A. (2021): “Algorithmic Pricing Facilitates Tacit Collusion: Evidence from E-Commerce,” Working paper.
  35. OECD (2017): “Algorithms and Collusion: Competition Policy in the Digital Age,” Technical report.
  36. Parkes, D. C. (2004): “On learnable mechanism design,” in Collectives and the Design of Complex Systems, Springer, 107–131.
  37. Possnig, C. (2023): “Reinforcement Learning and Collusion,” Working paper.
  38. Tumer, K. and N. Khani (2009): “Learning from actions not taken in multiagent systems,” Advances in Complex Systems, 12, 455–473.
  39. Tuyls, K., P. J. Hoen, and B. Vanschoenwinkel (2005): “An Evolutionary Dynamical Analysis of Multi-Agent Learning in Iterated Games,” Autonomous Agents and Multi-Agent Systems, 12, 115–153.
  40. Watkins, C. J. and P. Dayan (1992): “Q-learning,” Machine learning, 8, 279–292.
  41. Wunder, M., M. L. Littman, and M. Babes (2010): “Classes of Multiagent Q-learning Dynamics with epsilon-greedy Exploration,” in Proceedings of the 27th Annual International Conference on Machine Learning, 1167–1174.
Citations (6)

Summary

  • The paper demonstrates that spontaneous coupling drives unintended collusion among learning algorithms through reinforcement-based updates.
  • It uses a fluid approximation to convert a stochastic framework into a continuous model for analyzing strategic algorithm interactions.
  • The study finds that uneven learning rates lead to higher cooperation rates, highlighting the need for regulatory shifts in algorithmic markets.

Analysis of Strategic Interactions and Collusion Among Learning Algorithms

Introduction

Recent advancements in AI have led to the widespread deployment of algorithmic solutions across various sectors, particularly in setting prices and defining market shares. This paper develops a model that elucidates the strategic interactions between learning algorithms, unlocking insights into the phenomenon of algorithmic collusion. Unlike traditional forms of collusion that depend on explicit agreements or tacit understanding among human-based entities, algorithmic collusion stems from the intrinsic characteristics of the learning algorithms themselves. This paper coins the term "spontaneous coupling" to describe a novel mechanism through which independent, myopic algorithms synchronize their strategies to achieve collusive outcomes, without any programmed intent to do so.

Model Overview

At the heart of our analysis lies the concept of the reinforcer, a class of learning algorithms characterized by their reinforcement of successful actions through payoff-based updates. This reinforcement process, governed by a policy function, trades off exploration and exploitation to maximize payoff. By employing a fluid approximation technique, we transition from a discrete, stochastic framework to a deterministic continuous model, facilitating the analytical examination of the learning dynamics.

Key Findings

We demonstrate that spontaneous coupling manifests under certain conditions, leading to cooperation rates higher than those predicted by Nash equilibria in games such as the Prisoner's Dilemma. Our model reveals that the phenomenon hinges on the discrepancy in learning rates across different actions within the algorithms. Specifically, when learning rates are uneven, algorithms tend to synchronize their actions, resulting in collusive outcomes characterized by periodic cycles of high cooperation rates. Notably, algorithms with uniform learning rates across actions are immune to spontaneous coupling, underscoring the importance of learning rate configurations in preventing inadvertent collusion.

Implications for Algorithmic Markets

Our findings have profound implications for both the theoretical understanding and practical design of algorithmic markets. The identification of spontaneous coupling as a catalyst for collusion challenges the prevailing regulatory framework, which traditionally focuses on intent and explicit coordination among market participants. Thus, our model underscores the need for a regulatory paradigm shift to address collusion in algorithmic settings. Furthermore, by elucidating the mechanics of spontaneous coupling, this paper lays a foundation for developing strategies to mitigate or prevent collusive outcomes in markets dominated by algorithmic players.

Future Directions

This paper opens new avenues for research into the dynamics of learning algorithms in strategic settings. Future work could explore the robustness of spontaneous coupling across a wider array of game theoretic models and examine the sensitivity of collusive outcomes to variations in algorithm design parameters. Additionally, investigating countermeasures, such as modifications to learning algorithms or market design interventions, to prevent or mitigate algorithmic collusion presents a fruitful direction for subsequent research.

Conclusion

In conclusion, this paper offers a groundbreaking perspective on the dynamics of learning algorithms in competitive environments, unveiling the spontaneous coupling mechanism as a novel driver of algorithmic collusion. By bridging the gap between theoretical models and real-world phenomena, this research not only enhances our understanding of algorithmic behavior in markets but also prompts a reevaluation of regulatory approaches to safeguard competition in the digital economy.